CEI Joins Committee for Justice Coalition Letter on Antitrust

Photo Credit: Getty

View Full Document as PDF

Dear Representatives Buck, Biggs, and Gaetz:

We, the undersigned, write with sincere appreciation for your careful attention and participation on the House Judiciary Committee’s Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial, and Administrative Law. We are a group of legal experts, economists, and consumer and taxpayer advocates who believe in the importance of promoting competitive markets and defending the rule of law.

The Subcommittee’s 16-month-long investigation on competition in the digital marketplace raises important questions. Unfortunately, the Majority Staff’s Report and Recommendations overshoot those questions with recommendations that would radically upend antitrust law from protecting consumers to punishing successful and innovative businesses.

As we begin a year with a new Congress, a new president, and new challenges in antitrust policy, litigation, and legislation, we would like to take a moment to review some of the Subcommittee’s findings, recommendations, and the reports this process produced.

INTRODUCTION & SUMMARY

As you noted in your separate report, the Majority Staff’s recommendations include “sweeping changes” that “could lead to overregulation and carry unintended consequences for the entire economy.” In addition to being a self-described “attack on how America has approached antitrust for the past 40 years,” the report serves as a Trojan Horse for policies that are, at best, tangentially related to competition law, such as reducing certain procedural obstacles to litigation and banning arbitration clauses to create an easy path for class action lawsuits. The implications of the report extend far beyond just “Big Tech.”

We thank you for not signing onto those recommendations and identifying proposals of your own. We agree with the spirit of those alternative proposals but remain concerned that many of them pose a danger to the rule of law and threaten to upend decades of hard- won progress. Furthermore, these recommendations rely on mistaken assumptions made by those arguing in favor of drastic reform proposals.

More specifically, we are concerned that the recommendations identified in the Third Way Report as “Common Ground” would lead to the same outcome as the Majority Report, as these identified proposals would create a license for ideologically-driven mischief, invite “creative lawyering” in the courts, and untether antitrust from a standard that offers an objective and evidence-based framework for analysis.

Ultimately, we worry that both reports support proposals that place government bureaucrats at the heart of decisions regarding the way products are designed, how firms compete, and other questions that have been traditionally left to consumers. And through the adoption of these proposals, conservatives risk playing into the regulation-happy hands.

THE REPORTS: CONCERNS AND CONSIDERATIONS FOR FURTHER INQUIRY

The Third Way Report referenced a “need for clarification and expert feedback on majority proposals.”5 We would like to focus primarily on several proposals identified as “Common Ground” between the Majority Report and the Third Way Report as a starting point for such feedback and analysis and continue to provide constructive input.

I. We disagree with both reports’ recommendations to shift the burden of proof for companies pursuing mergers and acquisitions.

Approaches to antitrust enforcement based on presumptions of anticompetitive harm drastically upend core tenets of our legal system by inverting the burden of proof and diminishing the role of the federal judiciary.

Both reports recommend radical changes that would amend Section 7 of the Clayton Act to shift the burden in mergers by placing “the burden of proof upon the merging parties to show that the merger would not reduce competition.”

Inverting the basic notion that the government bears the ultimate burden of proof and thereby creating an end-run-around the consumer welfare standard, all to solve a problem that does not exist in merger litigation, is not a proposal that should withstand scrutiny by conservatives.6

II. The underlying justifications for burden shifting are demonstrably false and will impact competition in every sector.

Both reports justify shifting the evidentiary burden of proof by disparaging M&A reviews by federal agencies during an alleged time of a “mergers and acquisitions buying spree.” The Majority Staff points out that since 1998, the four digital platforms examined in the report were able to acquire more than 500 other companies. The report did not point out that this is only an average of less than six mergers or acquisitions per company per year, hardly a buying spree.

Furthermore, according to the Institute for Mergers, Acquisitions, and Alliances, there have been 894,669 worldwide acquisitions since 1998, an average of 40,667 annually.7 Thus the four digital platforms examined in the report have only accounted for .06 percent of acquisitions.8

Despite the small percentage of deals by the firms in question, the Third Way Report raises concerns of widespread lax enforcement of antitrust law, noting that: “Of course, many of these deals were either pro-competitive or competitively benign, but the important point here is that we have no real way of knowing what their competitive effect was because they were not reviewed by the antitrust cops on the beat.”

However, under current antitrust law, enforcers have adequate power to intervene.9 The FTC and the DOJ have only lost four cases in the last decade, and private litigants continue to bring monopolization claims.10 Outside of the courtroom, multitudes of mergers and anticompetitive actions are prevented by party abandonment out of fear of government action.

The proposed burden shifting provisions would affect a large swarth of deals across other industries, reducing competition while creating greater incentives for the government and private plaintiffs to file suit. It would also create a feeding frenzy for plaintiffs’ attorneys.

Both reports begin by recognizing that some of the most groundbreaking and innovative developments spearheading the economy have been in the tech sector. It would be a tragedy to assume anticompetitive conduct and to then apply this misguided view to other sectors across the economy. Yet both reports’ sweeping statements about the need for more antitrust enforcement under a wholly modified, unrecognizable antitrust regime poses that exact risk.

III. Market definition plays a critical role in antitrust analysis.

Both reports recommend that Congress clarify “that market definition is not required for proving an antitrust violation, especially in the presence of direct evidence of market power.” But as Andrew Lautz explains:

This is a dangerous recommendation, given that some of the more overzealous antitrust challenges in recent years have come as a result of antitrust agencies poorly or inadequately defining the market. Indeed, improper definition of the relevant market was a major theme of a recently proposed acquisition from the global distribution system company Sabre, of a much smaller travel company. Antitrust agencies must define a relevant market to determine if a merger or acquisition will be anticompetitive, and the Subcommittee is somewhat absurdly suggesting that market definition is not necessary to judge evidence of market power.11

Indeed, as Ronald Coase pointed out: “[I]f an economist finds something – a business practice of one sort or other – that he does not understand, he looks for a monopoly explanation. And as in this field we are rather ignorant, the number of ununderstandable practices tends to be rather large, and the reliance on monopoly explanations frequent.”12

For instance, in FTC v. Qualcomm, the FTC and the district court wrongly defined Qualcomm’s market. They mislabeled the company’s customers as its competitors. The Ninth Circuit corrected that poor analysis, which would have forced Qualcomm and other innovators in their telecom equipment sector to change lawful business practices and wrongly exposed them to antitrust liability.

Traditionally, market definition is framed around a static product with a distinct type of customer. With advances in technology, this build-and-freeze model breaks down as technologies evolve, and regulators are struggling to apply the correct framework.13 The correct response to this struggle, however, it not to abandon the practice of defining the relevant market in antitrust analysis. This would lead to inconsistencies in the application of antitrust laws that would negatively impact small companies across all sectors of our economy.

THE STATE OF THE DEBATE: PUTTING RECENT PROPOSALS INTO PERSPECTIVE

During the 1986 Supreme Court confirmation hearings for then-Judge Antonin Scalia, he was asked about his views on antitrust. “In law school, I never understood [antitrust law],” Scalia explained, “I later found out, in reading the writings of those who now do understand it, that I should not have understood it because it did not make any sense then.”

The need to bring coherency to antitrust law through a neutral underlying principle that cannot be weaponized is what led to the adoption of the modern consumer welfare standard.14 It is broad enough to incorporate a wide variety of evidence and shifting economic circumstances but also clear and objective enough to prevent being subjected to the beliefs of courts and enforcers.15

The consumer welfare standard has greatly benefited antitrust and is underappreciated as a significant narrowing of federal government power in the last half century and a major victory for the conservative legal movement.16 Recent proposals would upend decades of progress, returning antitrust to the era of favoring “small dealers and worthy men”17 regardless of factors such as efficiency, quality, and price.

We fear that today, both sides of the aisle are pushing for the weaponization of antitrust, either as a tool to punish corporate actors with whom they disagree or out of a presupposition that big is bad. Unfortunately, the antitrust debate has begun to devolve into a litany of unrelated and often contradictory concerns, unsubstantiated and dismissive attacks, and seemingly a presumption that any market-related complaint that can be made on the internet can also be cured by the panacea of antitrust.

This highly-charged atmosphere has led to radical proposals that run contrary to economic evidence and endanger significant advances made in antitrust scholarship. The adverse effects of such changes would reach well beyond today’s target du jour to firms in all sectors of our economy.

CONCLUSION

The House Committee on the Judiciary — and specifically the Subcommittee on Antitrust, Commercial, and Administrative Law — has an important role to play in this discussion. While there are many issues plaguing our society today, we believe that this Committee is equipped to examine antitrust soberly and without misdirection from legitimate anger over other issues which antitrust is not designed to address.

As you rightly note in your report, the Majority Report’s current proposal lacks clarity and requires additional refinement. Again, we applaud your work in highlighting important concerns with the Majority’s Staff recommendations and championing an alternative course. We hope you will consider our suggestions in refining an alternative.

We look forward to supporting efforts to create strong, evidence-based proposals and stand ready to assist in any way that is helpful. Please feel free to contact us should you have any questions or requests for additional input. We welcome the opportunity to further discuss these views and relevant proposals or assessment.

Sincerely,

Ashley Baker

Director of Public Policy

The Committee for Justice

Brandon Arnold

Executive Vice President

National Taxpayers Union

Robert H. Bork, Jr. President

The Bork Foundation

Jon C. Caldara

President

Independence Institute Denver, Colorado

James Czerniawski

Tech and Innovation Policy Analyst

Libertas Institute

James Edwards

Executive Director

Conservatives for Property Rights

Richard A. Epstein

The Laurence A. Tisch Professor of Law, New York University School of Law

The Peter and Kirsten Bedford Senior Fellow, The Hoover Institution

The James Parker Hall Distinguished Service Professor of Law Emeritus and Senior Lecturer, The University of Chicago

Tom Giovanetti

President

Institute for Policy Innovation

Douglas Holtz-Eakin

President

American Action Forum

Jennifer Huddleston

Director of Technology and Innovation Policy

American Action Forum

Curt Levey

President

The Committee for Justice

Ed Martin

President

Phyllis Schlafly’s Eagle Forum

Katie McAuliffe

Executive Director

Digital Liberty

Doug McCullough

Director

Lone Star Policy Institute

Jessica Melugin

Director, Center for Technology and Innovation

Competitive Enterprise Institute

Steve Moore

President

Committee to Unleash Prosperity

Grover Norquist

President

Americans for Tax Reform

Yaël Ossowski

Deputy Director

Consumer Choice Center

Eric Peterson

Director

Pelican Center for Technology and Innovation

Steve Pociask

President / CEO

American Consumer Institute

Jason Pye

Vice President of Legislative Affairs

FreedomWorks

Thomas A. Schatz

President

Council for Citizens Against Government Waste

Daniel Schnieder

Executive Director

American Conservative Union

NOTE: Organizations listed for identification purposes only.