CEI’s James Broughel Comments on Proposed Guidance for Assessing Changes in Environmental and Ecosystem Services in Benefit-Cost Analysis

Photo Credit: Getty

September 18, 2023

Docket ID: OMB–2022–0016

Request for Comments on Proposed Guidance for Assessing Changes in Environmental and Ecosystem Services in Benefit-Cost Analysis

Comments Prepared by James Broughel, Competitive Enterprise Institute

The Competitive Enterprise Institute (CEI) is a non-profit public interest organization committed to advancing the principles of free markets and limited government. CEI has a longstanding interest in applying these principles to the rulemaking process and has frequently commented on issues related to oversight of rulemaking and regulatory analysis. I am pleased to provide comments to the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) and the Office of Science and Technology Policy (OSTP) on their joint effort to create new guidance for assessing changes in environmental and ecosystem services in benefit-cost analysis. 

The Proposed Guidance for Assessing Changes in Environmental and Ecosystem Services in Benefit-Cost Analysis (hereafter referred to as the draft guidance) purportedly aims to improve how environment-related costs and benefits are captured in federal benefit-cost analyses. The draft guidance is a first of its kind, developed to fulfill directives found in a 2022 executive order on strengthening forests and communities facing stress from wildfires and climate change. The draft guidance also serves as a complement to other ongoing efforts by the Biden Administration, such as a strategy to develop environmental statistics for inclusion in national economic accounts, as well as efforts by OIRA and the White House to transform the regulatory review process.

This comment makes three key points: 

  • First, the need for this draft guidance has not been demonstrated. It appears to offer few novel insights beyond what is found in other OIRA circulars. Indeed, it repeatedly directs readers to read those other documents. Despite referencing OIRA Circular A-4 many times, however, the draft guidance does not clarify which version is being cited (the 2003 version or the update that is in-process). This limits the ability of the public to provide useful comments. At a minimum, proposing the draft guidance before the Circular A-4 update is complete is premature, as the two documents could end up being inconsistent with one another. Moreover, if the information contained in the draft guidance is important, it should appear as an amendment or appendix to Circular A-4, rather than as a standalone new document. The fact that the draft guidance was left out of the ongoing update to Circular A-4 suggests OIRA and OSTP may have wanted it to fly under the radar, or that they believe the draft guidance would not have survived the scrutiny accompanying that update. 
  • Second, the draft guidance needs to better distinguish between different forms of natural capital and the corresponding stream of consumption benefits they provide over time. This comment provides a framework for how OIRA and OSTP staff can do that.
  • Third, by conflating different types of natural capital, the draft guidance runs the risk of codifying irrationality into the rulemaking process, thereby institutionalizing cognitive bias in rulemaking. If finalized, this guidance and the policies it would help shape would provide a powerful example of a “behavioral government failure” in federal regulatory policy. 

The techniques included in the draft guidance lack a sound economic basis. At best, the draft guidance will be ignored or spread confusion throughout federal agencies. At worst, it will lead to systematic bias in the regulatory process and a significant misallocation of societal resources. Either way, the draft guidance should be rescinded.

That said, there is some useful information contained in the draft guidance, particularly as pertains to quantifying and describing nonmarket impacts, and detailing the ways ecosystem services can indirectly impact market prices. However, OIRA and OSTP should remove any discussion from the draft guidance about monetizing natural assets whose returns are completely unpriced in markets, and these agencies should append the remaining useful information to existing circulars instead of issuing a new guidance document. At the end of this comment, I explore alternative ways to monetize nature that are superior to the methods presented in the draft guidance.

The Office Tasked with Managing Paperwork Burdens Should Not Be Creating More Unnecessary Paperwork

The first question that arises upon a reading of the draft guidance is why it is even needed. On the face of it, it seems like yet more paperwork emanating from the federal bureaucracy. Ironically, OIRA itself was created by the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1980, which, as the name implies, was aimed at reducing paperwork burdens imposed by the federal government. Yet, paperwork burdens have hovered between 10.0 and 11.6 billion hours annually in recent years, and—despite going down in some recent years—have generally been going up steadily in the years since OIRA’s inception.  

Table 1: Paperwork Burden Changes by Category, FY 2018 thru FY 2021 (million hours)

Source: Office of Management and Budget. “Information Collection Budget of the United States Government. 2018-2021.”

Meanwhile, paperwork appears to be rising at OIRA as well. OIRA’s Circular A-4 regulatory guidance has recently ballooned from 48 to 91 pages in its new draft form. The ecosystems services draft guidance adds another 76, including all the various appendices. At the same time, the annual paperwork report from OIRA, known as the Information Collection Budget, has been late in recent years, suggesting that managing paperwork burdens may not be a priority at OIRA or that this statutory goal is being supplanted or made secondary to other non-statutory goals. 

Page counts are not so important if the pages contain valuable information. However, many experts agree the proposed updates to Circular A-4 will make regulatory analysis worse, not better. The same is likely true of the draft guidance, as this comment will explain in subsequent sections. In fact, it appears even OIRA has some doubts about the rigor of this document. It is odd, for example, that OIRA, at the same time it is updating Circular A-4, chooses not to include the information in the draft guidance as part of that effort. 

Consider the Federal Register notice announcing the draft guidance: 

The proposed Guidance is intended to be fully consistent with—and a faithful application of—the principles and guidelines in Circulars A–4 and A–94. Much in the proposed Guidance cross references applicable sections in Circular A–4—and, per a paragraph on page 1, analogous sections of Circular A–94—to address certain analytical steps.

In the quoted passage above, OIRA makes clear the draft guidance directs readers to other resources a number of times throughout. In fact, OIRA Circular A-4 is referenced repeatedly in the draft guidance. Yet, the draft guidance never makes clear what version of Circular A-4 is being cited. This is a problem because Circular A-4 is in the process of being updated. Given the close relationship between OIRA Circular A-4 and the draft guidance, proposing the draft guidance is premature and limits meaningful public involvement. By not clarifying what A-4 document is being referenced, commenters have no idea what document is being referred to. This undermines the ability of the public to provide useful comments, and prevents OIRA and OSTP from receiving the most useful comments.  

It makes sense, at a minimum, to delay proposing the draft guidance until the update to Circular A-4 is complete. Otherwise, the two guidance documents may not be consistent with one another when they are issued in final form. Furthermore, OIRA Circular A-4 already includes information about the valuation of nonmarket benefits, including environmental benefits. Useful information in the draft guidance could easily be included in that document. The fact that OIRA and OSTP chose to create an entirely new document for information that is clearly relevant to an ongoing, separate proceeding suggests these agencies may not believe the draft guidance could have survived the added scrutiny that the Circular A-4 update is receiving relative to this proposal. 

In short, the relationship between the draft guidance and Circular A-4 appears not to be well thought out. Moreover, for reasons outlined below, it is difficult to see how the draft guidance will improve decision making. Contrary to assertions by some of the authors of the draft guidance that more reading will lead to better decision making in this case, this document appears to be yet another unneeded circular, constituting what Harvard law professor and former OIRA Administrator Cass Sunstein calls “sludge.” Unless OIRA and OSTP can come up with a credible explanation to justify this added paperwork, including what value it adds beyond existing documents and why that information belongs in new guidance as opposed to in existing circulars, the draft guidance should be withdrawn. 

Three Classes of Natural Capital

Ecosystem services are, according to the draft guidance, “contributions to human welfare from the environment or ecosystems.” Natural capital is a concept closely related to ecosystem services, and refers to the stock of natural resources that society is endowed with. It too provides a range of benefits that contribute to human well-being. While the draft guidance does include a brief classification scheme for distinguishing between some of the different forms of natural capital and ecosystem services, this scheme is seriously incomplete for the purposes of valuing resources for their inclusion in a benefit-cost analysis. 

The reason the classification scheme is incomplete is that the draft guidance conflates natural capital whose returns are directly or indirectly priced in markets with natural capital whose returns are completely unpriced and disconnected from market activity. This conflation occurs through the practice of monetizing and aggregating these different types of capital stocks and flows. To be clear, the draft guidance does recognize that “the ways that ecosystem services relate to markets vary,” and that ecosystem services can contribute to human welfare with or without markets as intermediaries, but it fails to distinguish between the very different streams of consumption benefits that ecosystem services and natural capital generate over time. This is a critical oversight. The stream of consumption benefits that a natural capital asset produces over its lifespan can vary dramatically, and the methods by which OIRA recommends monetizing benefits paper over these differences. 

One source of clarity on this topic is the work of economist F. A. Hayek. In his 1930s book, Prices and Production, he explained how the quantity of consumer goods generated by a capital investment is an increasing function of time. Hayek’s fundamental insight was captured in a now-iconic triangle diagram, which illustrated the relationship between capital investment, time, and output in the form of consumer goods. 

For modern purposes, the diagram offers a clear and intuitive representation of the opportunity cost of capital (see figure 3), only in this case the “triangle” is actually the area under an exponential function curve. Hayek’s insights on capital have largely been lost by modern mainstream economists. However, a more generalized form of Hayek’s framework can help OIRA and OSTP distinguish natural capital assets based on the consumption streams they produce. 

Consider that the consumption benefits (or “goods”) derived from nature come in three basic forms: First are fleeting, temporary pleasures, like a sunset or a birdcall. These look a lot like consumption that occurs in markets in the sense that the benefit derived is a fleeting experience that occurs and then is over (figure 1). However, market and nonmarket consumption are not identical, because with nonmarket consumption no money is turned over in the “exchange.” The “seller,” in this case nature, can’t reinvest any of the proceeds. Second, are enduring nonmonetary benefits that can be appreciated day after day, such as the Grand Canyon’s awe-inspiring vista. These are ongoing benefits, rather than temporary ones, but the benefit is more or less the same year after year (figure 2). Again, returns to the seller can’t be reinvested because exchanges don’t take place with money, causing the returns to remain roughly constant each period. Third, are financial gains from commercialized resources like timber or fisheries. This last category of benefit is fundamentally different than the first two. Since money can be reinvested, returns magnify over time in a compounding fashion (figure 3). However, you can’t reinvest a scenic view or a birdcall.

As should be evident from these illustrations, the benefit stream a natural capital asset generates looks very different depending on whether its returns involve money and whether they are ongoing or temporary. These distinctions are rarely accounted for in government economic analysis, however. In fact, the three classes of returns are routinely conflated, as is the case throughout the draft guidance. The draft guidance notes ways that “[m]arkets reveal the marginal value of some ecosystem services,” and encourages these market prices to be used as part of valuation methods. But the guidance also goes on to explain how “ecosystems directly provide services to individuals and households without market intermediaries.” It then explains ways these impacts can be monetized, and finally it recommends all the different types of impacts be aggregated together in a single “accounting statement” that involves “one presentation of net benefits.”

Such a mingling of impacts, even when monetized, involves making apples to oranges comparisons. Under OIRA’s separate effort to update Circular A-4, the agency actually makes an even worse mistake, encouraging government analysts to treat a dollar of consumption and a dollar of investment equally (or nearly equally). This is bad economics. An invested dollar can generate more consumption than a dollar spent on consumption, and a dollar invested in assets generating financial returns can produce more consumption over time than a dollar invested in natural capital assets whose returns are completely unpriced in markets, by virtue of the ability to reinvest returns. 

Much better than OIRA and OSTP’s approach would be adopting Hayek’s perspective on capital and bringing the notion of opportunity cost (i.e., what would happen with resources in the future) to the forefront of economic analysis, rather than relegating the concept to the sidelines as the draft guidance now does. This would constitute a significant breakthrough for OIRA and OSTP. To start, this means recognizing that for each unit of capital displaced as well as created by government policy, a stream of consumption is generated, and the time stream of this consumption looks very different depending on the type of capital asset that is involved.

The Draft Guidance Codifies a Behavioral Government Failure

Behavioral biases are systematic deviations from rationality in judgment. Sometimes these biases can be attributed to heuristics, or mental shortcuts, that people make in decision making. Such biases include confirmation bias, over-optimism, loss aversion, and countless other cognitive imperfections, that can cloud judgment, making individuals prone to errors and leading them to make decisions that might not be in their own best interests.

Just as individuals exhibit behavioral biases, governments too act irrationally at times. This tends to occur when policies are influenced by the cognitive biases of policymakers or when policies are shaped by institutional forces that produce outcomes akin to the biases found in individual decisions. For instance, Cass Sunstein highlights how government agencies sometimes overestimate risks due to availability heuristics, leading to regulations that are costlier than necessary. This might occur because policy makers themselves are irrational in their responses to high-profile events, or because the political process gives incentives to policymakers to “do something” even when the best option is to wait or to do nothing. In each case, the policy outcome is suboptimal. 

When government interventions create inefficiencies or otherwise lead to an allocation of resources that is worse than what would occur absent the intervention, a “government failure” is said to occur. Such failures can result from factors like lack of information, bureaucratic inefficiencies, or political or special interest pressure that diverts policies from achieving the public interest. However, government failures also result from behavioral biases, leading to what is known as a “behavioral government failure.” 

There is a legitimate danger that the draft guidance will institutionalize behavioral bias in the federal rulemaking process. As with the discussion in the previous section, these problems relate to the manner in which environmental assets and their returns are monetized by federal agencies. The approach recommended throughout the draft guidance involves basing valuations on the preferences of current individuals, as stated in surveys or revealed through their actions in the marketplace. This is problematic because the value of a resource to any particular individual tends to differ from the value society should use, and a broad social perspective is what is called for in benefit-cost analysis.  

Here is an example. An individual might value a beautiful sunset more than an investment yielding a low one percent annual return. Why? Due to his finite lifespan and the natural human propensity toward impatience, the individual might not be willing to wait around for the low-yielding investment to pay off. The same cannot be said for society, however, which exhibits no human tendency for time preference, nor—short of human extinction—a finite lifespan. To attribute these characteristics to society is an example of “anthropomorphic bias,” which refers to the tendency to attribute human-like characteristics to non-human entities.

A nation like the United States can always wait for the low-yielding investments to pay their dividends. Current consumers tend to prioritize the short run. Yet, we must also respect the wishes and well-being of consumers in the future. A national benefit-cost analysis should not equate assets generating compounding financial returns with short-term consumption or even many sustained benefits derived from nature. (The reader is again referred to figures 1-3 in the previous section.) To do otherwise is to conflate individual and societal values.

For similar reasons, present bias is evident in the draft guidance. Present bias refers to the tendency of individuals, when considering events at two moments, to give stronger weight to events as they become closer to the present. In simpler terms, people often prioritize immediate rewards over future benefits, even if the future benefits are more substantial. Natural capital assets yielding fleeting, short-run benefits should not be placed on equal footing with natural capital yielding ongoing, compounding returns. Yet this is precisely what the draft circular recommends through the monetization of these different assets and their comingling in a single net benefit estimate. The failure to appreciate the power of compound interest is sometimes called exponential growth bias. Opportunity cost neglect is yet another bias evident, not just in this guidance document but across OIRA policy in general. 

For practical purposes, the best option would likely be for OIRA and OSTP to have agencies simply quantify aspects of nature—including natural capital stocks and flows and our impact on them—but to avoid the monetization exercise unless what is actually being evaluated is money. The best parts of the draft guidance are those areas where the guidance directs agencies to quantify and describe ecosystem services benefits without monetizing them, as well as when the draft guidance describes indirect ways environmental assets impose financial benefits and costs.

Thus, there is practical and useful information contained in the draft guidance, but valuation methods based on market prices need to be distinguished from valuation methods derived from other sources, such as stated or revealed preference techniques. The outputs of these latter methods often cannot be compared in an apples-to-apples manner with market activity. Attempts to include monetized nonmarket environmental flows in national economic accounts are similarly mistaken.

To Monetize Nature, Privatize It

As should be evident from the previous discussion, there are significant challenges that arise in efforts to monetize aspects of nature not priced in markets. If the Biden administration is so concerned with monetizing nature, rather than create an unnecessary guidance document, OIRA and OSTP could instead recommend that federal agencies privatize some of the vast land resources under their control. Estimates vary, but the federal government owns about 640 million acres of land in the United States, which is approximately 28 percent of the total U.S. land area of 2.27 billion acres. The value of federal lands was estimated in 2015 to be worth about $2.6 trillion. 

These are rough approximations, and there is considerable uncertainty involved in estimating the value of federally-owned land. Still, it is clear the U.S. federal government owns considerable land wealth. According to one analysis, in terms of land area under their control “[the Bureau of Land Management] and the Forest Service are both larger than Texas. And the fourth largest agency, the National Park Service, is larger than all but four states, Alaska, Texas, California, and Montana, slightly larger than New Mexico’s 77.6 million acres.” 

Embarking on a massive privatization effort would monetize nature in a manner that is superior to the approaches outlined in the OIRA and OSTP draft guidance, in the sense that it is more consistent with sound economic principles. Beyond raising revenue, such a privatization effort would have the added benefit that it would create new markets for environmental amenities, thereby internalizing some of the externalities associated with these assets being outside of market activity and under government control. Such an effort would enable the operation of more complete and efficient markets, a primary aim of benefit-cost analysis.

Conclusion

The draft guidance, as well as the larger effort it is part of to expand the use of green accounting in government, is a misguided endeavor. Arguably it is pseudoscience. Pricing the priceless probably only degrades nature while simultaneously leading to inefficient and irrational public policy decisions. 

Cost-benefit analysis can help guide sound policy when used judiciously. But OIRA and OSTP must also not fetishize monetization or believe equating incommensurable things reveals some deeper truth. Rather than continuing to resort to accounting gimmickry that has no sound basis in economics, OIRA and OSTP should go back to basics. 

The draft guidance could be improved by removing any and all discussion of monetizing those natural capital and environmental ecosystem services benefits and costs taking place entirely outside of markets. Even then, the useful information that remains should be included as an appendix or an amendment to existing circulars. The draft guidance itself must be withdrawn.  

Sincerely,

James Broughel, PhD