ISO14000: Environmental Regulation By Any Other Name

 

THE GREENING OF INDUSTRY

Over the course of the past 25 years, the governments of most developed countries have imposed increasingly stringent environmental regulations on businesses. To a large extent, this regulatory activity reflected an upsurge in concern for the impact of industrial activity both on the natural environment andhuman health. Until recently, most environmental regulations took the form of uniform industry standards. However, it is now becoming apparent that these “command and control” style regulations are a costly and inefficient means of achieving environmental objectives. In particular, such standards are inflexible, unresponsive and they often fail to take account ofthe actual environmental problems:

1. Inflexibility: national or international standards tend to ignore variations in the ability of firms to reduce their emissions. As a result, they impose higher costs on some firms than on others, often driving small firms out of business and concentrating output in the hands of a select few businesses. This effect has sometimes been countered by imposing less stringent controls on small firms, but in so doing the ostensive objectives of the regulation are emasculated.

2. Lack of responsiveness: regulations tend to result in “technological lock-in,” that is to say they prevent firms from developing new technologies (some of which might result in less environmental damage).2 This occurs because the regulations tend to be based upon known technologies and therefore discourage investment in more efficient technologies. Of course, the problem is mitigated by competition amongst environmental interest groups and the producers of pollution abatement technologies, who have an incentive to encourage governments to adopt more stringent standards. However, this may result in over-regulation (for example, imposingregulations that entail virtually eliminating certain chemicals that, at the very low doses at which they are currently present, are not known to cause any harm or, at least, cause less harm than many other naturally occurring chemicals) and does not provide an appropriate incentive to generate technologies that would deal efficiently with the most pressing pollution problems.

3. Failure to take account of actual environmental impacts of emissions: Uniform emissions standards take no account ofthe natural variability in absorptive capacity ofthe environment or of variations in the human impact of emissions. An “end-of-pipe” standard that is appropriate for the control of effluent discharged into a slow-flowing river is unlikely to be appropriate for effluent discharged into a faster-flowing river. Similarly, an end-of-pipe standard that is appropriate for airborne emissions from a plant in a built-up area is unlikely to be appropriate for a similarplant in an uninhabited region, since the human impact of the second is likely to be considerably less.

As the high cost of “command and control”’ type regulations has become apparent, economists and others have devised alternative mechanisms for achieving environmental objectives. In particular, a number of so-called ‘market-based mechanisms’ have been devised which are intended to have the same or similar effects to traditional regulations but at much lower cost. The best known of these are pollution taxes and tradable emissions permits. These mechanisms ensure that the firms reduce emissions in the most efficient manner possible. Very few nations have introduced pollution taxes, although many taxes are now justified at least in part on the grounds that they reduce the incentive to pollute (the gasoline tax in Europe is a case in point). In general, environmental taxes to date have been too low to have a significant effect on emissions, although it seems likely that the new generation of such taxes, such as the taxes on landfill disposal in France and Britain, will have a more significant effect. Tradable emission permits, on the other hand, have been somewhat more successful .

Environmental Management and Labeling

Aside from these “economic instruments,” a number of other mechanisms have been proposed as means of protecting the environment. In particular, considerable attention has been given to the provision of reliable environmental information to consumers, under the premises that such information might enable consumers to choose the products that are most “environment friendly” and/or those that are produced by firms which have environmentally soundmanagementprocedures. As aresult, many governments and several private organizations developedenvironmental labelingprograms.7 In addition, both the European Union and the British Standards Institute (BSI) developed environmental management systems.

ISO14000

Concern that national environmental labeling andmanagement schemes might become technical barriers to trade led the International Organisation for Standardisation (ISO)’ to form Technical Committee 207 (TC207) in 1993, which was to develop international ‘consensus’ standards in the field of environmental management tools and systems. The ISO was founded in 1947 “to facilitate the international coordination and unification of industrial standards.” Standards being “documented agreements containing technical specifications or other precise criteria to be used consistently as rules, guidelines or definitions of characteristics, to ensure that materials, products, processes and services are fit for their purpose.”

The resultant series, ISO14000, is divided into a number of mutually dependent standards, including:

ISO14001, 4, 31 – environmental management

ISO14010-15 – environmental audits

ISO14020-25 – environmental labels and declarations

ISO14040-43 – life cycle assessment

Of these, only ISO14001 and documents directly supporting it (ISO 14004, 10, 11, 12) have been published; the others are in various stages

 of preparation. A brief description of each of these standards and a summary of the current state of their development as of November 1996 is provided in the Appendix. The primacy of the development of ISO 14001 suggests that it will be the principal mechanism within ISO 14000. Therefore much of the following discussion focuses on ISO 14001

The Objectives of ISO14000

TC207 has suggested that ISO 14000 is likely to have the following effects:

lead to the harmonization of national rules, labels, and methods;

minimize trade barriers and related complications;

promote predictability and consistency;

lead to improvement of environmental performance;

lead to effective maintenance of regulatory compliance;

establish a framework to move beyond compliance;

assist companies/organizations to demonstrate commitment;

assist companies/organizations to enhance public posture;

lend credibility to performance reporting;

support a worldwide focus on environmental management;

sensitize the internal culture in organizations to environmental matters;

promote a voluntary consensus standards approach to environmental improvement.

Two questions immediately arise on considering this list of purported benefits. First, to what extent is each member of the list really a (net) benefit? Second, will ISO14000 really achieve the designated end? To answer these questions, let us consider each “benefit” in turn.

Harmonization

The “harmonization of national rules, labels, and methods” sounds nice, but what does it actually mean? Does it mean that the rules, labels, and methods adopted in each country must be the same? If so, then how should an ISO standard account for the fact that circumstances differ from country to country? In particular, how should it account for the fact that differences in the natural environment and in the standards of living entail differences in the priorities accorded to particular environmental problems?

For instance, in Northern Europe and the U.S., many lakes are now more acidic than they were fifty years ago; some scientists have suggested that this acidification is, in part, the result of”acidrain.”In response, governments in Europe and the U.S. have imposed limits on the emissions of SO2 from industrial plants. However, in South America no such acid rain problem has been reported, so emissions limits are less stringent. It is clear that a rule covering both the US/Europe and South America would have to take account of this difference in environmental circumstances. Such a rule clearly could not dictate that emissions limits be set everywhere at the same level as in Europe or the US, since this would discriminate against South American producers. But setting the limit at the maximum allowed in the least regulated country would have no impact.

As it stands, ISO14001 (the environmental management standards) resolves this dilemma simply by requiring that firms implementing ISO 14001 employ management procedures in each plant that are consistent with the existing law and legislation in the particular country in which they operate. Of course, this begs the question of whether the legislation is fit for the task of protecting the environment, and, if so, whether it does so at least cost. In the U.S. at least, these assumptions cannot be taken for granted.

One of the reasons ISO 14000 has been suggested as an alternative to the traditional command-and-control type regulations is that these regulations are an inefficient mechanism for achieving environmental protection. So, to require compliance with these regulations as part of ISO14000 compliance seems rather perverse. In particular, it is likely to impose marginal costs in excess of the marginal benefits in many cases.

Paul Kupakuwana, who heads the Zimbabwe delegation to TC 207, has suggested that for firms in developing countries, ISO14000 will become a trade barrier because there might not be sufficient resources available to meet existing legislation. Concurring, Leonardo Cardenas, a Mexican delegate, argued that the main problem for firms in Latin countries is liquidity.Basically, firms in developing countries lack access to capital for implementing environmental compliance projects; whereas firms in developed countries have much easier access to capital for such projects.

In its favor, the requirement that firms comply with national legislation will shift some of the burden of enforcement from the nation’s regulators on to the national ISO registration body, thereby reducing the incentive for corruption within the regulatory agency. However, this benefit is unlikely to be great, since uptake of ISO14000 is not likely to be universal (unless it becomes mandatory) – indeed, if the experience of ISO9001 is anything to go by, uptake is likely to be restricted to a small minority of firms (only around 75,000 firms in the US have become registered under ISO9001), so the majority of firms will still be subject to monitoring and enforcement action under the conventional regulatory system. Again, this problem comes down to the cost of registration: “According to a survey conducted by Apple Computer for West Coast Working Group, an ISO 14000 interest organization, only 7 percent of respondents plan to seek ISO 14000 certification … The main objection that firms have with ISO certification is its expensive nature, as audits can cost as much as $15,000 per site averaging 100 employees.

The Impact of ISO14000 on International Trade

It is by now well established that international trade benefits poor and rich alike. However, there remain many constraints on such trade. One such constraint is differences in national standards. For example, criteria for the European Eco-Label tend to reflect conditions that are prevalent in Europe, to the possible detriment of firms outside Europe that operate under different conditions. For example, the Eco-Label for tissue paper includes criteria for emissions ofchlorinated organics and sulphur dioxide that reflect the concerns ofEuropean environmental activists but have little relevance in countries such as the United States, Canada, or Brazil. As a result, these ecolabel criteria create a bias in favor of paper produced in Europe and act as a de facto barrier to trade.18 Prima facie, it would seem that an international ecolabel might overcome this problem — by enabling a broader coalition of stakeholders to determine criteria. However, an international ecolabel is likely to create a more serious problem of technological lock-in than a national label. Since such lock-in wouldreduce the possibility for further advances in the international division of labor, the long-term effect of an international ecolabel could even be more detrimental than the long-term impact of a national label.

Moreover, if governments around the world required the firms from which they procured to be registered to ISO 14000, then the many firms in developing countries that could not afford registration would be at a disadvantage. As a result, ISO 14000 is likely to become a significant barrier to trade.

 

Predictability and Consistency

Predictability and consistency would seem to be desirable; clearly consumers are likely to benefit from any system that enables them more simply to purchase products that satisfy their desire to protect the environment. However, if ISO14000 registration is not the best mechanism for ensuring that firms behave in an environmentally responsible manner in all circumstances, then some consumers will purchase products manufactured in ways that are predictably and consistently less environment friendly than they have been led to believe. The attempt to provide predictability and consistency itself results in firms becoming locked into particular production processes and products, reducing the level of technological innovation and thereby harming the environment.

Lock-in by ISO14000

Lock-in occurs for many reasons. In some cases, being locked into a particular path of technology might not cause too many problems, especially where the lock-in has occurred only as a result of the voluntary decisions of market participants. However, where lock-in is induced by the state, then it is unlikely to be so benign.

ISO14001’s management standards will increase the cost of implementing changes to production processes, since “environmental management” mustbe incorporated regardless ofits effectiveness. As aresult, the rate of investment in research and development is likely to fall and fewer advancements in technology will take place. Since technological advancements frequently result in environmental improvements (such as thinner garbage bags, lighter weight tin cans, concentrated washing powders, and more efficient combustion technologies), this is bad news for the environment.

IfISO 14000 remains apurely voluntary system, then firms will weigh up the costs of registering against the alternatives (such as continued regulatory enforcement) and choose their cheapest option. However, if the decision to register is the result of any measure of coercion (such as the threat of more stringent environmental regulations), then the problem ofregulatory¬induced lock-in will worsen.

The problem of regulatory-induced lock-in would be even more severe if nations demanded that products bare an ISO 14031 environmental label. To see how badly this might affect us, consider the impact such a label might have had if it had been imposed on laundry detergents 30 years ago:

Product development would have been directed towards conforming with actual and expected ecolabel criteria, which could only have been based on the technology available at the time. In addition, detergent manufacturers are likely to have shifted investment in R&D away from laundry detergents and onto less risky products. Under such circumstances, it seems unlikely that today’s detergents would be much different from those available twenty years ago: bulky powders, which, lacking enzymes, required high-temperatures (60C or more) for most washes.

Now, compare this scenario with what actually happened.

The introduction of laundry detergents containing enzymes and other improved cleaning technologies has enabled better cleaning at lower temperatures. As a result, consumers use less electricity—thereby saving them money, consuming fewer natural resources and emitting fewer chemicals into the atmosphere and watercourses. Indeed, this single innovation, which might well not have occurred had an ecolabel been in place (either because of fears concerning the environmental impact of enzymes or simply because of lack of investment in R&D), has reduced electricity consumption in Europe so much that without it approximately six medium-sized, new power stations would have been required (estimate by scientists at P&G Europe).

The Impact of ISO14000 on Environmental Performance.

Improvement in the environmental performance of firms is clearly desirable and would seem to be the primary objective of ISO14000. Yet, if the arguments above hold, then the probability is that ISO 14000 will have the opposite effect. Of course, the environmental performance of some firms may well improve as a result of implementing ISO14000. For such firms, some form of environmental management system is probably desirable. Whether

ISO 14001 is the most cost-effective system remains in doubt; however, those firms that had not considered any environmental management system prior to the implementation of ISO14001 and do experience both a reduction in overall cost and an environmental improvement could be said to have benefited from implementation. Yet it seems likely that such firms will be in the minority and, by and large, ISO 14000 registration will be an overly costly means of achieving environmental improvement for a few firms. As a result, ISO 14000 registration is likely to result in the misallocation of resources and, in the long-term, have a negative impact on the environment.

The Impact of ISO14000 on Regulatory Compliance

The question of whether regulatory compliance is desirable is beyond the scope of this paper; clearly some form of control on the activities of firms is desirable. Unconstrained, firms would have little incentive to prevent pollution; whether constraint comes from government regulators or through the private law courts is another matter.

Effective maintenance of regulatory compliance can only be ensured by monitoring the activities of firms. The notion that merely introducing an environmental management system might ensure compliance seems absurdly optimistic. Even if it were the case that a management system couldbe devised that wholly obviated the need for monitoring compliance with particular regulations, it would still be necessary to monitor the management system itself. Essentially, ISO 14001 shifts some ofthe burden ofcompliance monitoring away from the state’s regulatory agency onto the administrator responsible for ensuring compliance with ISO14001. ISO14001 does not provide a framework for moving “beyond compliance.”

ISO14000 as a Market Signal

It would be desirable if companies that are providing genuine environmental improvements were able to signal this to consumers in some way. Of the mechanisms proposed in the ISO14000 series only those on certification of environmental claims would seem to fit this bill .22

Whether ISO 14000 registration improves the public perception of a firm will be a function ofmany things. Since ISO 14000 registration is unlikely to be beneficial to the environment and may result in increased costs to the consumer and create a barrier to trade for firms in developing countries, consumers should be informed that ISO 14000 registration is nothing to be proud of.

Will ISO14000 lend credibility to performance reporting?

ISO14000 is inflexible: criteria take years to develop and are not changed for several years thereafter (the standards are up for revision in 1999). As a result, it is likely that developments in the science ofenvironmental reporting will overtake the standard. Moreover, environmental audits are based on the same subjective assessments that so bedevil life cycle analysis.2~ As aresult, any credibility gainedby the use ofISO14000 to backenvironmental audits would be based on misleading information.

ISO14001 and the Promotion of Environmental Management

ISO 14001 is likely to increase companies’ awareness ofenvironmental management, especially if registration is made a criterion of procurement policies. However, this is not necessarily a good thing because the focus of ISO14001 is too narrow. Companies will be encouraged to comply with ISO14001, but not necessarily to think holistically about improving their performance by using resources more efficiently. ISO 14001 is one particular kind of environmental management scheme, it is not the only kind; ISO 14001 may crowd out other, perhaps superior methodologies for developing environmental management programs.

ISO14001 will only sensitize the internal culture of firms to environmental matters if that internal culture has not already been sensitized. Since ISO 14001 is most likely to be implemented in large industrial concerns and since most of these are likely already to have some kind of resource-efficiency culture (otherwise they would not have got where they are), the number of firms that develop environmental management programs from scratch as a result ofISO 14001 is likely to be small. Moreover, some firms that implement ISO 14001 may end up replacing an environmental management program that is specifically tailored to the firm’s peculiarities with one that is more easily audited, but less suitable, to the firm in question.

The Impact on Business

“[ISO14000] may be used by companies and organizations to better manage [sic] their environmental affairs and to show a commitment to environmental protection.

“Implementation of ISO 14000 could become a condition of business loans to companies that aren’t even involved in international trade.

“Insurance companies may lower premiums for those who have implemented the standard.

“ISO 14000 maybecome acondition ofsome customer/ supplier transactions, especially in Europe and with the US government.

“Evidence of conformance to ISO 14000 may factor into alternative regulatory programs, the exercise of prosecutorial and sentencing discretion, and into government consent decrees and other legal instruments.

“In the courts, ISO 14000 may become a standard of due care in assessing whether company was in good faith making consistent and diligent efforts to manage it environmental impact.

“In multilateral trade agreements, there is a high probability that the ISO 14000 standards will become a factor in establishing whether governments are actually making an attempt to improve the environmental situation within their countries.

“In terms of international aid and loans, the World Bank and other financial institutions may qualify their loans to less developed countries and begin to use the ISO 14000 standards as an indicator of commitment to environmental protection.”

THE BENEFITS OF ISO STANDARDS

We now consider to what extent these are real benefits and whether ISO14000 standards, and in particular the ISO 14001 standards for environmental management, are likely to achieve them.

Better Management through ISO14000 ?

On the face of it, one could hardly object to the use of ISO14001 management standards by some companies to manage better their environmental affairs. If the procedures provide firms with a discipline that enables them to discover superior management strategies, then all well and good. However, any firm considering such a path should consider the relatively high cost of implementing ISO 14001 (about $15,000 for a firm of around 100 employees – see above) and perhaps consider alternative options, such as the use of an internal life-cycle analysis (LCA) which might identify key areas where waste is occurring (see below).

ISO14001 as a ConditionforProcurement, Businessloans andInsurance.

It is possible, even likely, that some companies and governments will require ISO 14000 certification as a prerequisite for procurement. However, it is not clear that this is desirable. Most firms are likely to comply with the spirit of ISO 14000 —– in particular, the requirement of achieving continuous environmental improvement–as amatter ofcourse, regardless ofany external guidance, since environmental improvements suchas using fewerraw materials tend to be in the financial interests of the firm and can generate good will and reinforce a positive public image. But ISO 14001 involves a costly auditing procedure that might actually result in the redirection of resources away from investment in more environment friendly processes. Moreover, there is no obvious reason why a firm with ISO 14001 certification should be any more committed to environmental improvement than a non-certified firm. This fact has been recognized by B&Q, a British chain of hardware stores that has led the way in the provision of such items as “sustainably sourced” hardwood. B&Q does not favor ISO14001 certification. Instead it carries out its own environmental audits based on what it sees as the key environmental issues for any particular firm or product.24 The possibility that governments might require ISO 14001 certification is more disturbing. Given the market power of most governments, in areas where the government has the majority market share (such as, in most developed countries, the provision of medical care and education) the impact on firms could be devastating, with small firms likely to be most affected.

Given the high costs of implementing ISO 14001, it would be rather perverse to require implementation of ISO14000 as a condition of business loans to companies. Of course, ISO 14001 registration might act as a signal to banks and insurers that the firm is a lower risk than other firms in a class. However, it is not clear that this risk is directly related to the impact a firm will have on the environment. If that was the case, banks and insurers would require firms to carry out environmental audits that are tailored to their own needs, rather than the more general (and costlier) ISO 14001 audit. It seems more likely that ISO 14001 would reduce the credit and insurance risk of a business by providing a signal of regulatory compliance to the state.

All this suggests that ISO14000 is likely to exaggerate divisions within markets, creating an “underclass” of firms that cannot afford to implement ISO14000. These firms will be subject to more regulatory supervision and will be convicted more frequently of environmental crimes.

ISO14000 and WTO

The suggestion that ISO14000 might figure in international trade agreements as “a factor in establishing whether governments are actually making an attempt to improve the environmental situation within their countries,” is cause for concern. The cost of becoming registered under ISO 14000 is high in developed countries; in less developed countries the cost of registration is likely to be astronomic. It is unlikely that there will be a large supply of qualified auditors. So, once again, a methodology developed in the North25 (and one which is probably inappropriate there) will be imposed unwillingly on the people of the South. Indeed, the use of ISO14000 as a condition in an international trade agreement would be nothing short of environmental imperialism. Under WTO rules, ISO14000 should not be allowed as part of any government’s procurement policy; in particular, given the dubiousness of the claim that ISO14001 registration will lead to environmental improvement, requirement of ISO 14001 should not qualify as an exception under Article XX of GATT.

The suggestion that the World Bank, the IMF and other International institutions might demand that governments require ISO 14000 registration by firms from which they procure is not surprising. Loans from these institutions have often merely been an excuse to benefit firms whose parent companies are in developed countries. Since it is these Northern firms that are most likely to be able to afford ISO14000 registration, the imposition of an ISO 14000 condition would merely perpetuate this imperialist tradition. But, in any event, the real problem with loans from the World Bank, the IMF, and other multilateral lending institutions, is not the conditions they impose but the fact that they are only granted to governments, which tend to disburse the resources in ways which are not particularly beneficial to the people.26

More Fundamental Problems with ISO14000

It might appear that most of the criticisms above have focused on problems that might be addressed by restructuring ISO 14000 in some way, so that it does not discriminate against firms in developing countries or against smaller firms in general. For example, it couldbe envisagedthat disadvantaged firms might receive a subsidy towards the cost of ISO 14000 registration. In fact, such a system has already been developed in Canada – the government of Nova Scotia has announced that it is to give firms a tax credit of 25 percent on costs related to ISO14000 registration up to a maximum of $150,000.27

However, several more fundamental problems exist with ISO14000. First, the environmental audits carried out for registration under ISO14001 might not actually leadto an improvement in a firms environmental performance. The main reason for this is that the auditors might not identify the most appropriate areas for reducing environmental impacts. This problem is itself a function of the trade-offs that are inherent to any environmental issue. For example, consider a firm thatproduces extrudedplastic tubes. Newtechnologies might enable the firm to produce tubes of a similar strength using less virgin material. However, a firm carrying out an environmental audit might notice that a considerable amount of material is wasted during the cutting process (where tubes are cut to the length demanded by consumers); As a result, the audit firm may recommend that an environmental improvement would include reuse of this scrap material. However, inclusion of scrap in the production of new tubes is likely to alter the properties of the plastic, requiring that the tubes be thicker in order to provide an equivalent performance. As a result, the overall use ofraw materials might fall slightly, but the total amount ofmaterial used in each tube has increased so the energy required for producing the tubes is likely to have risen. The use of raw materials and the consumption of energy might both be considered “environmental impacts”, so there is an obvious trade-off between consumption of raw material and consumption of energy. However without further information it is not possible to know whether the addition of recycled material increases or reduces the environmental impact. Suppose that the energy used for producing the tubes comes from oil. Burning this oil means consuming a scarce resource and, possibly, causing some air pollution. This hypothetical example is mirrored in the real world by the experience of a Californian company that makes garbage bags (see box on facing page).

Is ISO14000 registration beneficial to firms?

At base, the problem with ISO14000 comes down to this: Any improvement that might be recommended as environmentally superior by an

 

ECOLABELS AND ENVIRONMENTAL TRADEOFFS:

THE CASE OF GARBAGE BAGS

Awarding ecolabels on the basis of a single criterion such as “recycled content” may encourage consumers to purchase products that do not necessarily provide significant benefits over alternatives. Sometimes, such ecolabels may even hinder environmental progress.

Consider, for example, the tradeoff between recycled content and source reduc¬tion for plastic garbage bags. The State of California mandates that garbage bags thicker than 0.75 mm must contain a minimum of 20 percent recycled content, increasing to 30 percent in January 1997. Before the law took effect, many firms had reduced the thickness of their garbage bags from between 1.5 and 2 mm to under 1 mm. This conserved between 100 and 200 million pounds of virgin plastic resin. However, these new, lighter-weight bags cannot maintain the same product performance if they contain recycled material. This is largely because the recycled resin cannot perform within the same performance parameters as virgin resin.

First Brands Corporation experimented with incorporating recycled material into their bags. They used their own plastic scrap, which was of relatively high-quality since it was a uniform material and had only undergone the process of thermal degradation once (compared to the three or four times that is common for post-consumer recycled plastic). The bags made in this manner exhibited 25 to 65 percent strength loss, resulting in holes in the bags, tearing, and separation of the plastic layers. In sum, First Brands used the cleanest, purest recycled material available yet still could not make a bag with adequate strength to hold garbage.

To compensate for these problems, First Brands had to make thicker bags, using more total material in order to meet the mandatory recycled content required in California. The company now runs two separate product streams – one for California and one for the rest of the nation. Higher production costs (resulting from shorter runs for the recycled-content bags), and additional material costs mean Californian consumers are paying more for thicker, poorer-quality garbage bags that use more total resources. First Brands still receives complaints from Californian consumers who say that even the bags made from the heavier (thicker) material fall apart. Ironically, before the Californian law was imposed, entrepreneurs, testing the competitive marketplace, had already attempted to introduce bags that used post-consumer recycled plastics. But these bags held less than ten percent of market share, suggesting that only the ‘evergreens’ were buying them.

This example demonstrates some of the complexities associated with reducing the environmental impacts of products. A single-criterion ecolabel obscures these complexities. In California, the net effect of the mandatory recycled content law is that newer, lighter garbage bags that represent a technological advance over earlier bags are locked out of California’s market. Companies are forced to adapt their product line at higher costs to consumers, with no net environmental benefits. Ecolabels, which typically are awarded to products on the basis of a narrow range of criteria, have similar effects.

Source: Personal interview by Lynn Scarlett with Bob Vetere, First Brand Corp., Conn. Adapted from J. H. Morris and L. Scarlett, Buying Green – Consumers, Product Labels and the Environment (Los Angeles: Reason Foundation, November 1996).

 external auditor is likely to based on that auditor’s subjective assessment of environmental problems. Regional biases may also affect the objectivity ofthe audit process. Finally, we must recognize that environmental priorities change over time with the expansion of scientific knowledge and the evolution of societal preferences. Any formalized audit process risks lagging behind these changes. The only alternative to this is that the auditor focuses exclusively on the problem of reducing the overall costs of the firm. Indeed, many protagonists of ISO14000 have touted this as a prime benefit of registration. However, ISO14000 is not the only system that has been developed to improve a company’s performance. Internal life cycle analyses have been carried out by firms since the early 1970s as a means of identifying areas where firms can reduce costs and increase output.

A voluntary alternative to regulations?

Dr. John Gibbons, head of the White House Office of Science and Technology, noted that “the [ISO14000] process must be voluntary: ISO should not become a prescriptive mechanism used to enforce environmental compliance. It is an alternative, not an addition, to the command-and-control system and should not become another burden imposed by government on industry on top of other regulatory, permitting, and reporting requirements.” 

It is very important that ISO14000 be voluntary, for any sort of compulsion to implement ISO14000 (or even a system in which preferential treatment was given to firms complying with ISO14000) might seriously distort the market and lock in a potentially inferior approach to environmental management. As the above discussion has indicated, the cost of complying with ISO14000 is likely to vary considerably between industries and firms. Moreover, for many firms, compliance with ISO14000 may not be the most environmentally sound way of investing resources. Compulsory compliance with ISO14000 would discriminate against firms that were complying with regulations but which had no formal environmental management procedure. In such cases, compliance might mean that resources are diverted away from investments that lead to environmental improvements (such as the light-weighting of products) towards pointless changes to management and accounting procedures.

ISO 14000 purports to provide an alternative to regulation, a “market based” solution to environmental problems. In reality, at best it is likely to be little more than an invitation for auditors to make a few more bucks. At worst, it will result in environmental imperialism, restricting trade and imposing unnecessary costs on firms in developing countries that will lose out relative to firms in developed countries.